Post-Autistic Economics Network
Click here
to subscribe for free
to the
Real-World Economics Review formerly
Post-Autistic Economics Review
and receive immediate access to the current
issue
Real-World Economics Review
Home Page of PAE
Network
|
www.paecon.net
Post-Autistic Economics Review
Kicking Away the Ladder:
How the
Economic and Intellectual Histories of Capitalism Have Been Re-Written to
Justify Neo-Liberal Capitalism
Ha-Joon Chang (Cambridge University, UK)
There is currently great pressure on developing countries to
adopt a set of “good policies” and “good institutions” – such as
liberalisation of trade and investment and strong patent law – to foster
their economic development. When some developing countries show reluctance in
adopting them, the proponents of this recipe often find it difficult to
understand these countries’ stupidity in not accepting such a tried and
tested recipe for development. After all, they argue, these are the policies
and the institutions that the developed countries had used in the past in
order to become rich. Their belief in their own recommendation is so absolute
that in their view it has to be imposed on the developing countries through
strong bilateral and multilateral external pressures, even when these
countries don’t want them.
Naturally, there have been heated debates on whether these
recommended policies and institutions are appropriate for developing
countries. However, curiously, even many of those who are sceptical of the
applicability of these policies and institutions to the developing countries
take it for granted that these were the policies and the institutions that
were used by the developed countries when they themselves were developing
countries.
Contrary to the conventional wisdom, the historical fact is that
the rich countries did not develop on the basis of the policies and the
institutions that they now recommend to, and often force upon, the developing
countries. Unfortunately, this fact is little known these days because the
“official historians” of capitalism have been very successful in re-writing
its history.
Almost all of
today’s rich countries used tariff protection and subsidies to develop their
industries. Interestingly, Britain and the USA, the two countries that are supposed to have reached the summit
of the world economy through their free-market, free-trade policy, are
actually the ones that had most aggressively used protection and subsidies.
Contrary to the
popular myth, Britain had been an aggressive user, and in certain areas a pioneer, of
activist policies intended to promote its industries. Such policies, although
limited in scope, date back from the 14th century (Edward III) and the 15th
century (Henry VII) in relation to woollen manufacturing, the leading industry of
the time. England then was an exporter of raw wool to the Low Countries, and Henry VII for example tried
to change this by taxing raw wool exports and poaching skilled workers from
the Low Countries.
Particularly between
the trade policy reform of its first Prime Minister Robert Walpole in 1721
and its adoption of free trade around 1860, Britain used very dirigiste trade and industrial policies, involving
measures very similar to what countries like Japan and Korea later used in order to develop their industries. During this
period, it protected its industries a lot more heavily than did France, the supposed dirigiste counterpoint to its free-trade, free-market
system. Given this history, argued Friedrich List, the leading German
economist of the mid-19th century, Britain preaching free trade to
less advanced countries like Germany and the USA was like someone trying to
“kick away the ladder” with which he had climbed to the top.
List was not alone
in seeing the matter in this light. Many American thinkers shared this view.
Indeed, it was American thinkers like Alexander Hamilton, the first Treasury
Secretary of the USA, and the (now-forgotten) economist Daniel Raymond, who first
systematically developed the infant industry argument. Indeed, List, who is
commonly known as the father of the infant industry argument, in fact started
out as a free-trader (he was an ardent supporter of German customs union – Zollverein) and learnt about this
argument during his exile in the USA during the 1820s
Little known today,
the intellectual interaction between the USA and Germany during the 19th century did not end there. The
German Historical School – represented by people like Wilhelm Roscher, Bruno Hildebrand, Karl Knies,
Gustav Schmoller, and Werner Sombart
– attracted a lot of American economists in the late 19th century.
The patron saint of American Neoclassical economics, John Bates Clark, in
whose name the most prestigious award for young (under 40) American
economists is given today, went to Germany in 1873 and studied the German
Historical School under Roscher and Knies, although he gradually drifted away from it.Richard Ely, one of the leading American
economists of the time, also studied under Knies
and influenced the American Institutionalist School through his disciple, John Commons. Ely was one of the founding fathers of the American Economic
Association; to this day, the biggest public lecture at the Association’s
annual meeting is given in Ely’s name, although few of the present AEA
members would know who he was.
Between the Civil
War and the Second World War, the USA was literally the most heavily protected economy in the world.
In this context, it is important to note that the American Civil War was
fought on the issue of tariff as much as, if not more, on the issue of
slavery. Of the two major issues that divided the North and the South, the
South had actually more to fear on the tariff front than on the slavery
front. Abraham Lincoln was a well-known protectionist who cut his political
teeth under the charismatic politician Henry Clay in the Whig Party, which
advocated the “American System” based on infrastructural development and
protectionism (thus named on recognition that free trade is for the British
interest). One of Lincoln’s top economic advisors was the famous protectionist economist,
Henry Carey, who once was described as “the only American economist of
importance” by Marx and Engels in the early 1850s
but has now been almost completely air-brushed out of the history of American
economic thought. On the other hand, Lincoln thought that
African Americans were racially inferior and that slave emancipation was an
idealistic proposal with no prospect of immediate implementation – he is said to have emancipated the
slaves in 1862 as a strategic move to win the War rather than out of some
moral conviction.
In protecting their
industries, the Americans were going against the advice of such prominent
economists as Adam Smith and Jean Baptiste Say, who
saw the country’s future in agriculture. However, the Americans knew exactly
what the game was. They knew that Britain reached the top through protection and subsidies and therefore that they needed to do the same if they were going to get
anywhere. Criticising the British preaching of free trade to his country,
Ulysses Grant, the Civil War hero and the US President between 1868-1876, retorted
that “within 200 years, when America has gotten out of protection all that it can offer, it too will
adopt free trade”. When his country later reached the top after the Second
World War, it too started “kicking away the ladder” by preaching and forcing
free trade to the less developed countries.
The UK and the USA may be the more dramatic examples, but almost all the rest of
the developed world today used tariffs, subsidies and other means to promote
their industries in the earlier stages of their development. Cases like Germany, Japan, and Korea are well known in this respect. But even Sweden, which later
came to represent the “small open economy” to many economists had also
strategically used tariffs, subsidies, cartels, and state support for R&D
to develop key industries, especially textile, steel, and engineering.
There were some exceptions like the Netherlands and Switzerland that have maintained free trade since the late 18th
century. However, these were countries that were already on the frontier of
technological development by the 18th centuries and therefore did
not need much protection. Also, it should be noted that the Netherlands deployed an impressive range of interventionist measures up
till the 17th century in order to build up its maritime and
commercial supremacy. Moreover, Switzerland did not have a patent law until 1907, flying directly against
the emphasis that today’s orthodoxy puts on the protection of intellectual
property rights (see below). More interestingly, the Netherlands abolished its 1817 patent law in 1869 on the ground that
patents are politically-created monopolies inconsistent with its free-market
principles – a position that seems to elude most of today’s free-market
economists – and did not introduce another patent law until 1912.
The story is similar
in relation to institutional development. In the earlier stages of their
development, today’s developed countries did not even have such “basic”
institutions as professional civil service, central bank, and patent law. It
was only after the Pendleton Act in 1883 that the US federal government started recruiting its employees through a
competitive process. The central bank, an institution dear to the heart of
today’s free-market economists, did not exist in most of today’s rich
countries until the early 20th century – not least because the
free-market economists of the day condemned it as a mechanism for unjustly
bailing out imprudent borrowers. The US central bank (the Federal Reserve Board) was set up only in
1913 and the Italian central bank did not even have a note issue monopoly
until 1926. Many countries allowed patenting of foreign invention until the
late 19th century. As I mentioned above, Switzerland and the Netherlands refused to introduce a patent law despite international
pressure until 1907 and 1912 respectively, thus freely “stole” technologies
from abroad. The examples can go on.
One important
conclusion that emerges from the history of institutional development is that
it took the developed countries a long time to develop institutions in their
earlier days of development. Institutions typically took decades, and
sometimes generations, to develop. Just to give one example, the need for
central banking was perceived at least in some circles from at least the 17th
century, but the first “real” central bank, the Bank of England, was
instituted only in 1844, some two centuries later.
Another important
point emerges is that the levels of institutional development in today’s
developed countries in the earlier period were much lower than those in
today’s developing countries. For example, measured by the (admittedly highly
imperfect) income level, in 1820, the UK was at a somewhat higher level of development than that of India today, but it did not even have many of the most “basic”
institutions that India has today. It did not have universal suffrage (it did not even
have universal male suffrage), a
central bank, income tax, generalised limited liability, a generalised
bankruptcy law, a professional bureaucracy, meaningful securities
regulations, and even minimal labour regulations (except for a couple of
minimal and hardly-enforced regulations on child labour).
If the policies and institutions that the rich countries are
recommending to the poor countries are not the ones that they themselves used
when they were developing, what is going on? We can only conclude that the
rich countries are trying to kick away the ladder that allowed them to climb
where they are. It is no coincidence that economic development has become
more difficult during the last two decades when the developed countries
started turning on the pressure on the developing countries to adopt the
so-called “global standard” policies and institutions.
During this period, the average annual per capita income growth
rate for the developing countries has been halved from 3% in the previous two
decades (1960-80) to 1.5%. In particular, Latin America virtually stopped growing, while
Sub-Saharan Africa and most ex-Communist countries have experienced a fall in
absolute income. Economic instability has increased markedly, as manifested
in the dozens of financial crises we have witnessed over the last decade
alone. Income inequality has been growing in many developing countries and
poverty has increased, rather than decreased, in a significant number of
them.
What can be done to change this?
First, the historical facts about the historical experiences of
the developed countries should be more widely publicised. This is not just a
matter of “getting history right”, but also of allowing the developing
countries to make more informed choices.
Second, the conditions attached
to bilateral and multilateral financial assistance to developing countries
should be radically changed. It should be accepted that the orthodox recipe
is not working, and also that there can be no “best practice” policies that
everyone should use.
Third, the WTO rules should be re-written so that the developing
countries can more actively use tariffs and subsidies for industrial
development. They should also be allowed to have less stringent patent laws
and other intellectual property rights laws.
Fourth, improvements in institutions should be encouraged, but
this should not be equated with imposing a fixed set of (in practice, today’s
– not even yesterday’s – Anglo-American) institutions on all countries.
Special care has to be taken in order not to demand excessively rapid
upgrading of institutions by the developing countries, especially given that
they already have quite developed institutions when compared to today’s
developed countries at comparable stages of development, and given that
establishing and running new institutions is costly.
By being allowed to
adopt policies and institutions that are more suitable to their conditions,
the developing countries will be able to develop faster. This will also
benefit the developed countries in the long run, as it will increase their
trade and investment opportunities. That the developed countries cannot see
this is the tragedy of our time.
___________________
Ha-Joon Chang (hjc1001@econ.cam.ac.uk) teaches in the
Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge. This article is based on his new book, Kicking
Away the Ladder – Development Strategy in Historical Perspective, which was published by Anthem Press, London, on 10 June 2002.
SUGGESTED
CITATION:
Ha-Joon Chang, “Kicking Away the Ladder”, post-autistic economics review, issue no. 15, September 4, 2002, article 3. http://www.btinternet.com/~pae_news/review/issue15.htm
|